HEALTHPLANUSA . NET |
QUARTERLY NEWSLETTER |
Community For Affordable Health Care |
Vol VII, No 2, July, 2008 |
Utilizing the $1.5 Trillion Information Technology Industry
To
Transform the $2 Trillion HealthCare Industry into Affordable HealthCare
In This Issue:
1. Featured Article:
Moral Health Care vs. “Universal Health Care”
2. In the News:
California’s payroll soars under Schwarzenegger
3. International
Medicine: Canadian Health Care Lies in Ruins
4. Medicare: A Short
History of Government Health Care in the United States
5. Lean HealthCare:
The Most Energetic Area of Lean Practice
6. Medical Myths: Who pays for the uninsured?
7. Overheard on
Capital Hill: An Obituary: Neoconservatism
8. What's New in US
Health Care: The Presidential Elections
9. Health Plan USA:
Disruptive Technology: Not All Patients Want High-Tech Care
* * * * *
1. Feature Article: Moral Health Care vs.
“Universal Health Care”
This
article is from TOS Vol. 2. Winter
2007–2008Vol. 2, No. 4 Full contents of the issue are listed here.
Although American scientists, doctors, and businessmen
have produced the most advanced medical technology in the world, American
health care is in a state of crisis. Technologically, we are surrounded by
medical marvels: New “clot buster” drugs enable patients to survive heart
attacks that once would have been fatal; new forms of “keyhole surgery” enable
patients with appendicitis to be treated and discharged within twenty-four
hours, whereas previously they would have spent a week in the hospital;
advances in cancer treatment enabled bicyclist Lance Armstrong to beat a
testicular cancer, which, had he lived fifty years ago, would have killed him;
and so on.
From an economic perspective, however, such medical
treatments are increasingly out of reach to many Americans. Health care costs,
as reported by the New York Times, are rising twice as fast as
inflation.1 And health insurance, as reported by USA
Today, “is becoming increasingly unaffordable for many employers and
working people.” A decreasing percentage of employers are offering health
insurance benefits to their workers, and many of those who are offering
benefits are requiring their employees to pay a greater percentage of the
costs. The U.S. Census Bureau reported in 2007 that nearly forty-seven million
Americans had no health insurance, a sharp increase of ten million people from
a mere fifteen years earlier. In short, there is a major disconnect between
existing life-saving medical technology and the ability of Americans to afford
it.
This discord is affecting doctors as well. The
American Medical Association warns physicians that, due to the lack of
affordable health insurance, “more patients will delay treatment and . . .
doctors will likely see more uncompensated care.” Hence, each year doctors are
working harder and harder but making less and less money, resulting in a
“critical level” of stress and burnout. According to a recent survey of
doctors, “30 to 40 percent of practicing physicians would not choose to enter
the medical profession if they were deciding on a career again, and an even
higher percentage would not encourage their children to pursue a medical
career.”
Total spending on health care in the United States
amounts to nearly 17 percent of the entire economy, and this is expected to
rise to 20 percent by 2015, “with annual spending consistently growing faster
than the overall economy.” Because of skyrocketing health care costs, the U.S.
federal Medicare trust fund is expected to go bankrupt in 2019, less than
twelve years from now, potentially leaving millions of elderly Americans
without health insurance coverage. American health care is in dire straits and
will continue to worsen—unless Americans demand fundamental political change to
reverse the trend. Unfortunately, the kinds of changes currently being proposed
by politicians will only exacerbate the problem.
Politicians from across the political spectrum,
including Democratic presidential candidate Hillary Clinton and Republican
candidate Mitt Romney, have argued that the government should guarantee
“universal coverage” to all Americans, making health care a “right.” And
politicians are not alone; numerous businessmen, union leaders, and insurance
executives are united in saying that this will solve our problems.
It will not.
Contrary to claims that government-imposed “universal
health care” would solve America’s health care problems, it would in fact
destroy American medicine and countless lives along with it. The goal of
“universal health care” (a euphemism for socialized medicine) is both immoral
and impractical; it violates the rights of businessmen, doctors, and patients
to act on their own judgment—which, in turn, throttles their ability to
produce, administer, or purchase the goods and services in question. To show
this, we will first examine the nature and history of government involvement in
health insurance and medicine. Then we will consider attempts in other
countries and various U.S. states to solve these problems through further
government programs. Finally, we will show that the only viable long-term
solution to the problems in question is to convert to a fully free market in
health care and health insurance.
Although health care and health insurance are often
conflated, there is a crucial difference between the two. Whereas health care
consists of the actual goods and services necessary for medical care, health
insurance is one means of affording such care. The two are closely related but
distinct, as are the services of an auto-body repair shop and an automobile
insurance company. . .
In financial terms, Medicare and Medicaid are
bankrupting our state and federal governments. These two federal insurance
programs compose nearly 20 percent of the federal budget, and the percentage
keeps rising. In addition, for most states Medicaid is the largest single
budget item, averaging 22 percent of states’ spending. Medicaid is generally
administered by the state, with matching federal tax dollars. As a result,
states seek to expand Medicaid coverage and other medical programs such as
SCHIP (State Children’s Health Insurance Program) in order to reap more of the
matching federal dollars. Eligibility for these programs continues to expand,
and, in some states, families with incomes as high as $55,000 are now eligible
for Medicaid benefits. Federal, state, and local governments now pay 50 percent
of every dollar spent on health care, even though government health insurance
covers only 27 percent of the population. . .
Governments have further interfered with the free
market by means of health care mandates—governmental decrees regarding how
health care providers and patients can or must act. . .
There are as many as 1,900 separate mandates across
the country, and more than half the states have 35 or more mandates, with Idaho
having the fewest at 14 and Maryland having the most at 62. These mandates
violate the rights of insurers and customers to choose their own policies and
coverage. They limit an insurance company’s ability to offer inexpensive and
reduced benefit packages for the young and healthy, or to tailor policies to a
person’s needs or wants, or to offer low-cost, high-deductible policies that
cover only catastrophic events. They force unwanted coverage upon customers,
raise the costs of each insurance policy involved, and retard innovation in the
marketplace. . .
Several states, including Kentucky, Maine, and
Washington, have introduced mandatory guaranteed issue into their individual
insurance markets. After Kentucky introduced the mandate, forty-five of fifty
insurers withdrew from the market there, which, in turn, led to fewer options
and higher costs for consumers. In 2000, Kentucky eliminated the mandate,
hoping to recapture the competition and choice offered by its lost insurance market,
and since then several of the insurers have returned. Maine is now down to two
insurance companies, and rates have increased 124 percent in six years. The
state of Washington has seen the number of insurers decline from thirty to
seven while costs have increased. . .
With both mandates in place, those who are healthy
tend to wait until they get sick to buy insurance. There is no need to buy
insurance while you are healthy if insurance companies charge the same for sick
or healthy customers and if they are required to accept you as a paying
customer whenever you apply. These mandates quash the very purpose of
insurance, which is to spread risk among the healthy; their effect is to spread
health expenses among the sick and the less sick. This, in turn, requires
insurers to raise their rates or, if states prohibit higher prices, to leave
those states. . .
Bearing in mind what government intervention has done
to health insurance, let us turn to its effect on medicine.
As with health insurance, government has meddled in
the market for medical products and services for decades. Government routinely
violates the rights of doctors and other allied professionals by forcing them
to act against their best judgment; it regulates the licensing and practices of
professionals and facilities; it forces doctors and hospitals to offer services
without compensation; it subjects doctors to fines and jail terms for errors in
the documentation of patient records and claims; consequently, it stifles
productivity, hampers quality, increases the cost of medical goods and
services, and causes unnecessary suffering and death. In support of these
claims, let us look first at the laws regarding emergency room treatment and
medical record keeping. . .
One reason for the overcrowding and overuse of ERs is
the Emergency Medical Treatment and Labor Act of 1985 (EMTALA). This law
requires that hospitals that accept Medicare patients diagnose and treat anyone
who comes within two hundred feet of an emergency room, regardless of whether
the person can pay for the treatment. The effect of this law is that anyone can
walk into an emergency room at any time and receive treatment—without concern
for payment. If a bum wants a free meal and a warm bed for the night, all he
has to do is walk into the ER and say, “Doc—I feel like an elephant is sitting
on my chest!” By law, the emergency room doctor and staff have to run tests
until they can prove that he is not having a massive heart attack and can be
safely discharged. And the failure of a hospital or physician to comply with
any EMTALA-mandated responsibilities can result in fines of up to $50,000 for
each infraction.
Because of the low reimbursement rates paid by
Medicaid and Medicare, many recipients have no regular primary care physician
and can get decent care only through the ER. Medicaid compounds this problem by
not requiring patients to pay any deductibles or co-pays for emergency
room visits.
EMTALA enslaves doctors. . .
Another government-mandated problem for doctors and
hospitals is the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act (HIPAA).
Most people know of this act because of the paperwork everyone must now sign
when visiting a doctor’s office. Patients must acknowledge in writing their
right to medical privacy. Although this is just one more piece of paper for a
patient, it is hundreds more for each doctor, and thousands for each large
clinic or hospital. And HIPAA’s bureaucratic regulations do not merely mean
more paperwork.
A particularly onerous aspect of this coercion is that
doctors are subject to civil and criminal penalties for privacy errors in
record keeping. The federal Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) may
impose civil penalties of $100 per failure to comply with a privacy rule
requirement, up to a maximum of $25,000 per calendar year for multiple
violations. This means that a doctor may be subject to a fine if he forgets to
ask a patient to sign the HIPAA form, even if neither the doctor nor his staff
improperly releases any of that patient’s private information. And a doctor who
knowingly obtains or discloses individually identifiable health information in
violation of HIPAA faces a fine of $50,000 and up to one-year imprisonment.
An emergency room physician told one of the authors of
this article that he and his colleagues have to violate the criminal provisions
of HIPAA every day because, in order to save lives in an emergency situation,
ER physicians must routinely treat patients and release information to their
immediate family members without following the HIPAA documentation rules. It
would be immoral for ER doctors to strictly comply with the law, as it would
delay emergency medical treatment, keep families from understanding their
loved-one’s condition, and preclude the crucial sharing of knowledge between
family members and doctors about the history and condition of the patient. This
law (and others like it) turns doctors into criminals, not for providing
substandard medical treatment, but for failing to put government paperwork
ahead of the lives of their patients. Fortunately, most ER doctors are still
willing to put their patients’ lives ahead of paperwork, even when it means
violating federal law. .
Quoting Dr. Peikoff again:
And such charity, I may say, was always forthcoming in
the past in America. The advocates of Medicaid and Medicare under LBJ did not
claim that the poor or old in the ’60s got bad care; they claimed that it was
an affront for anyone to have to depend on charity.
But the fact is: You don’t abolish charity by calling
it something else. If a person is getting health care for nothing, simply
because he is breathing, he is still getting charity, whether or not any
politician, lobbyist or activist calls it a “right.” To call it a Right when
the recipient did not earn it is merely to compound the evil. It is charity
still—though now extorted by criminal tactics of force, while hiding under a
dishonest name.
As shown, charity already abounds in America and would
be even more abundant if the government removed its coercive hands from the
health care and health insurance industries and consumers. Even with the
government violating rights to the extent that it currently does, many examples
indicate the sufficiency of charity in this regard. Here are just a few: The
Shriners’ Hospitals provide free care to children and adults with orthopedic,
spinal cord, and burn injuries. St. Jude’s Hospital provides free catastrophic
care for children. Pharmaceutical companies provide enormous quantities of
prescription drugs to those who are unable to afford them; for instance, they
provided free (or nearly free) prescription drugs to about 6.2 million people
in 2003 alone, and have been providing free prescription medicines to those
unable to afford them for years. And there are hundreds of other examples.
With sufficient cultural support, eliminating EMTALA
would be easy and would cause little disruption of services. It could be phased
out over the course of a year with no difficulty. By setting a definite date in
the future, for example, December 31, 2008, at which EMTALA would end, everyone
would have ample opportunity to learn the law, and willing doctors, hospitals,
and philanthropic organizations would have time to ramp up their charity care.
. .
Further, we must eliminate all insurance
mandates—including mandatory community rating, guaranteed issue, guaranteed
renewability, and benefit mandates—and we must emphatically reject any call for
individual or employer mandates. Insurance companies have a moral right to offer
whatever policies and terms they deem marketable. Under a free market in health
care, the types of insurance plans and coverage will undoubtedly change, but
such changes will be the result of insurers and consumers acting according to
their best judgment—by mutual consent and in each party’s best interest. That
is the beauty of a truly free market.
Some states have already begun to curtail benefit
mandates. As we mentioned above, Kentucky called for a three-year moratorium on
all new mandates; consequently, the market in that state has begun to revive.
To enact such measures across the country and to sustain them over time,
however, Americans must come to understand that mandates are immoral and
impractical and that, consequently, they do harm, not good.
We must work toward the elimination of Medicare,
Medicaid, and all other government insurance programs that allegedly benefit
the aged and the poor. As we have seen, these programs provide illusory
“coverage,” while actually reducing or eliminating patients’ access to doctors.
These programs could be phased out over several years beginning with the
passage of a law to the effect that no person under the age of thirty-five will
pay into or receive any benefits from Medicare. This would enable those under thirty-five
to begin planning for their own future, long-term medical costs and enable
insurers to plan for the future as well. Likewise, we could start reducing both
the extent of Medicaid benefits and the number of beneficiaries, by limiting
the number of years that a person could receive Medicaid benefits, in ways
similar to those methods used very effectively by the Clinton administration to
reduce welfare rolls.
Finally, we must repeal HIPAA and all other government
regulations involving health insurance or medical care. It is immoral for
doctors to be subject to criminal penalties for documentation errors that
violate no rights and have nothing to do with the quality of patient care.
These laws do nothing but increase the amount of time spent on useless, or
nearly useless, paperwork. Eliminating HIPAA and many other regulations would
enable doctors to return to the practice of medicine, providing patients with
more access to quality care. Again, eliminating these laws could be done
easily, by setting forth a future time at which the law would expire. . .
Although the goal of these proposed changes—a fully
free market in health care and health insurance—cannot be achieved overnight,
movement in the right direction can and should begin immediately. The only
moral and practical way to proceed is to recognize the proper end and to
consciously and consistently move toward that end by taking whatever steps in
that direction are possible at any given time. What we must not do is
shy away from recognizing and proclaiming the proper goal—the complete
eradication of every trace of government interference in medicine and health
insurance—or the fundamental moral justification for pursuing that goal: the
individual’s moral right to his life, liberty, and property.
Only the ideal of the free market—based on the
principle of individual rights—provides a solid foundation for genuine and
practical reform. And only a free market in medicine can deliver the properly
(i.e., voluntarily) priced high-quality health care that Americans deserve.
This last point is evident in the sectors of medicine with the least government
regulation, such as cosmetic surgery and LASIK eye surgery. The clear pattern
in these sectors is a continual decrease in prices and improvement in quality.
As health economist Devon Herrick stated in testimony before the U.S. Congress:
[D]espite a marked increase in demand between 1992 and
the present, cosmetic surgeons’ fees remained relatively stable. . . Another
example of price competition is the market for corrective eye surgery. In 1999,
only a few years after LASIK was approved, the price was about $2,100 per eye,
according to the ophthalmic market research firm MarketScope. Within a short
time, competition drove the price down to slightly more than $1,600. The cost
per eye of the standard LASIK is now about 20 percent lower than six years
earlier. . .
In other words, the market can and does bring down
health care costs while improving services when allowed to operate without
government interference.
A free market in health insurance and health care
works because it recognizes that health care is a commodity produced by
individuals who have a right to offer that commodity for trade on whatever
terms they see fit—and that consumers have the right to accept or reject those
terms as they see fit. When all parties are free to trade voluntarily,
according to their own best judgment, the result is lower costs and higher
quality—a fact that is evident throughout the economy and recognized by all
reputable economists.
The relatively-free American marketplace has done a
magnificent job in providing other necessities of life such as food, shelter,
and clothing; it can do the same for health care and health insurance—if we
free up these markets.
In a truly free market, other creative and innovative
solutions will arise—solutions that have not yet been conceived by any
politician, policy analyst, or by the authors of this article. The fact that we
cannot foresee all the possible good ideas is not an undesirable “bug” of the
free market but rather one of its marvelous features. Just as someone twenty
years ago could not have imagined the specific innovations and benefits that
would arise from a free market in the then-fledgling internet industry
(consider eBay, Amazon.com, Google, iPhones, etc.), so people today cannot
imagine the specific innovations and benefits that would arise from a free
market in medicine and health insurance. What is certain is that the freer the
market, the more innovation and benefits will arise.
We have seen that the myriad problems with American
health care and health insurance are the result of decades of government
interference in the markets for these goods and services. The systematic
violation of the rights of health care providers and insurers to freely produce
and trade goods and services has created a dysfunctional system that has harmed
countless providers, insurers, employers, and patients.
We have also seen that more government control of
medicine and health insurance is not the solution. Evidence and logic show that
government interference in the market leads only to rising costs, rationing,
and needless suffering and death.
The current system is unsustainable. Unless policy
changes are made, American health care and health insurance will not remain in
their currently dysfunctional conditions; they will necessarily get worse
(recall that health care costs are rising far more rapidly than the rate of
inflation). One way or another, the current situation will change. We do not
have a choice in that matter, but we do have a choice as to the direction of
that change.
America stands at a crossroads. We can continue to
recycle the failed ideas of the past, continue to violate individual rights,
and impose more government control on medicine and health insurance in a futile
attempt to salvage a fundamentally flawed system by extending and building on
its flaws. Or we can stand on moral principle, respect individual rights, begin
dismantling the broken system, and start working toward a free and therefore
thriving market in medicine and health insurance.
If you enjoyed this article, why not make objective
journalism a staple in your life? Subscribe to The
Objective Standard today!
Email someone a link to this article by clicking here.
Lin
Zinser, JD, was a civil litigator for nineteen years. She recently created
Freedom and Individual Rights in Medicine (FIRM), an organization dedicated to
education and intellectual activism regarding the causes and solutions of the
current problems with health insurance and medicine. For more information on
FIRM, please visit www.WeStandFIRM.org.
Paul Hsieh, MD, is a practicing physician in the south Denver metro area. He is
also a founding member of FIRM.
Please go to www.theobjectivestandard.com/issues/2007-winter/moral-vs-universal-health-care.asp
to read the entire lengthy, well-documented important treatise and study it
critically to understand the reality of government health care.
* * * * *
2. In the News: California’s payroll soars under Schwarzenegger
State's payroll
soars under Schwarzenegger, Erin
McCormick, Chronicle Staff Writer SF Chronicle, Sunday, May 25, 2008
The state of
California's payroll is skyrocketing, even as its budget deficit has grown to
billions of dollars in recent months.
In Gov.
Arnold Schwarzenegger's first four years, the total bill for state workers'
salaries jumped by 37 percent, compared with a 5 percent increase in the
preceding four years under then-Gov. Gray Davis, a Chronicle analysis of state
payroll records shows.
[State of California's over-$100K
earners]
One month
before Schwarzenegger took office in November 2003, just eight state employees
earned more than $200,000 a year working in the core state government, which
excludes universities and the Legislature. In April of this year, there were
nearly a thousand, according to records.
And the
number of state employees making six-figure salaries has more than doubled
since 2003, to nearly 15,000. Meanwhile, the number of state workers has grown
by 26,000 under Schwarzenegger after being cut by Davis, who was recalled from
office in the midst of a severe budget crisis.
Some of the
pay increases in recent years have been out of Schwarzenegger's control, including
previously negotiated pay raises for some employee unions and court-ordered pay
hikes for medical workers in the state prison system that are estimated to have
cost the state hundreds of millions of dollars.
Also fueling
the spurt in payroll growth: salary increases for employees in a few
politically powerful labor unions, including the state's prison guards, as well
as pay hikes for workers in the upper echelons of state government. Elected
members of the Legislature, who will decide in the coming weeks how to resolve
the state's $17.2 billion deficit for the fiscal year beginning July 1, also
received increases last year.
"Salaries
have only gone one way - up," said Charles Murray, chair of the California
Citizens Compensation Commission, which sets pay for the state's top elected
officials. Murray, a Republican from San Marino (Los Angeles County), has
called for a pay cut for legislators and other elected officers in light of the
state's huge deficit.
"If we
had control over the janitors, I'd ask them to take a pay cut, too," he
said. "The reasoning is very simple: We're in big trouble moneywise."
Legislators,
gubernatorial aides and top medical professionals have received pay hikes in
the last 12 months. And as the state looks at drastic cuts in many programs,
the governor is proposing about $260 million in salary increases for the
state's prison guards, whose pay jumped about 34 percent in five years under
their previous contract.
At the same
time, pay for many lower-ranking civil service workers has not kept up with the
15 percent increase in the state's consumer price index in the past four years,
according to an analysis by the state Legislative Analyst's Office. Most civil
service workers saw their pay rise by only 12 percent over that time.
The winners
of the payroll race seem to be the unions with the strongest political ties or
those who spend big bucks on political contributions and lobbying, said
Christina Lokke of California Common Cause, a good-government watchdog group.
"There's
lobbying going on among all these groups of state employees - and the outcomes
are pretty imbalanced," she said. "Sometimes, politics and money beat
good policy, that's when the public loses out."
Schwarzenegger
spokesman Aaron McLear said much of the blame rests with the Davis
administration, which negotiated some contracts in which workers deferred
initial pay raises for bigger gains in later years. . .
California
Highway Patrol officers got a 32 percent pay increase over four years through a
contract negotiated by the Davis administration that linked their pay to the
five largest police departments in the state. The average officer now makes
$73,000 a year. The state's professional engineers received a 31 percent pay
raise through a similar automatic-increase mechanism negotiated by the
Schwarzenegger administration. . .
To read
examples of the salary hikes revealed in the state's payroll database and
compensation documents go to http://sfgate.com/cgi-bin/article.cgi?f=/c/a/2008/05/25/MNI610S459.DTL
-- How
much do state workers make? Search a database of the state's top
earners at: sfgate.com/webdb/statepay
E-mail Erin
McCormick at emccormick@sfchronicle.com.
www.sfgate.com/cgi-bin/article.cgi?f=/c/a/2008/05/25/MNI610S459.DTL&hw=Erin+McCormick&sn=001&sc=1000
It doesn’t make any difference which party is in office, both
increase government size and control.
We have to look for fiscally responsible candidates wherever we find them
* * * * *
3. International
Medicine: Canadian Health Care Lies in Ruins
As this presidential campaign
continues, the candidates' comments about health care will continue to include
stories of their own experiences and anecdotes of people across the country:
the uninsured woman in Ohio, the diabetic in Detroit, the overworked doctor in
Orlando, to name a few.
But no one will mention Claude Castonguay — perhaps
not surprising because this statesman isn't an American and hasn't held office
in over three decades.
Castonguay's evolving view of Canadian health care,
however, should weigh heavily on how the candidates think about the issue in
this country.
Back in the 1960s, Castonguay chaired a Canadian
government committee studying health reform and recommended that his home
province of Quebec — then the largest and most affluent in the country — adopt
government-administered health care, covering all citizens through tax levies.
The government followed his advice, leading to his
modern-day moniker: "the father of Quebec medicare." Even this title
seems modest; Castonguay's work triggered a domino effect across the country,
until eventually his ideas were implemented from coast to coast.
Four decades later, as the chairman of a government
committee reviewing Quebec health care this year, Castonguay concluded that the
system is in "crisis."
"We thought we could resolve the system's
problems by rationing services or injecting massive amounts of new money into
it," says Castonguay. But now he prescribes a radical overhaul: "We
are proposing to give a greater role to the private sector so that people can
exercise freedom of choice."
Castonguay advocates contracting out services to the
private sector, going so far as suggesting that public hospitals rent space
during off-hours to entrepreneurial doctors. He supports co-pays for patients
who want to see physicians. Castonguay, the man who championed public health
insurance in Canada, now urges for the legalization of private health insurance.
In America, these ideas may not sound shocking. But in
Canada, where the private sector has been shunned for decades, these are
extraordinary views, especially coming from Castonguay. It's as if John Maynard
Keynes, resting on his British death bed in 1946, had declared that his faith
in government interventionism was misplaced.
What would drive a man like Castonguay to reconsider
his long-held beliefs? Try a health care system so overburdened that hundreds
of thousands in need of medical attention wait for care, any care; a system
where people in towns like Norwalk, Ontario, participate in lotteries to win
appointments with the local family doctor.
Years ago, Canadians touted their health care system
as the best in the world; today, Canadian health care stands in ruinous shape.
Sick with ovarian cancer, Sylvia de Vires, an Ontario
woman afflicted with a 13-inch, fluid-filled tumor weighing 40 pounds, was
unable to get timely care in Canada. She crossed the American border to
Pontiac, Mich., where a surgeon removed the tumor, estimating she could not
have lived longer than a few weeks more.
The Canadian government pays for U.S. medical care in
some circumstances, but it declined to do so in de Vires' case for a
bureaucratically perfect, but inhumane, reason: She hadn't properly filled out
a form. At death's door, de Vires should have done her paperwork better.
De Vires is far from unusual in seeking medical
treatment in the U.S. Even Canadian government officials send patients across
the border, increasingly looking to American medicine to deal with their
overload of patients and chronic shortage of care.
Since the spring of 2006, Ontario's government has
sent at least 164 patients to New York and Michigan for neurosurgery
emergencies — defined by the Globe and Mail newspaper as "broken necks,
burst aneurysms and other types of bleeding in or around the brain." Other
provinces have followed Ontario's example.
Canada isn't the only country facing a government
health care crisis. Britain's system, once the postwar inspiration for many
Western countries, is similarly plagued. Both countries trail the U.S. in
five-year cancer survival rates, transplantation outcomes and other measures.
The problem is that government bureaucrats simply
can't centrally plan their way to better health care. . .
However the candidates choose to proceed, Americans
should know that one of the founding fathers of Canada's government-run health
care system has turned against his own creation. If Claude Castonguay is
abandoning ship, why should Americans bother climbing on board?
Gratzer is
a senior fellow at the Manhattan Institute and a physician licensed in both the
U.S. and Canada, where he received his medical training. His newest book,
"The Cure: How Capitalism Can Save American Health Care," is now
available in paperback.
To
read the entire report, go to
www.ibdeditorials.com/IBDArticles.aspx?id=299282509335931
Canadian Medicare does not give timely access to
healthcare, it only gives access to a waiting list.
--Canadian Supreme Court Decision 2005 SCC 35, [2005] 1 S.C.R. 791
http://scc.lexum.umontreal.ca/en/2005/2005scc35/2005scc35.html
To
read the Jacques Chaoulli, M.D. report, go to www.jpands.org/vol10no3/chaoulli.pdf.
* * * * *
4. Medicare: A Short History of Government Health Care in the
United States
How to Cure Health Care By Milton
Friedman, Hoover Digest
The United States spends a mind-boggling percentage of
its GDP on a health care system that virtually everyone agrees is a disaster.
Is there any way out of this mess? There is—and Hoover fellow Milton
Friedman has found it.
Since
the end of World War II, the provision of medical care in the United States and
other advanced countries has displayed three major features: first, rapid
advances in the science of medicine; second, large increases in spending, both
in terms of inflation-adjusted dollars per person and the fraction of national
income spent on medical care; and third, rising dissatisfaction with the delivery
of medical care, on the part of both consumers of medical care and physicians
and other suppliers of medical care.
Rapid
technological advances have occurred repeatedly since the Industrial
Revolution—in agriculture, steam engines, railroads, telephones, electricity,
automobiles, radio, television, and, most recently, computers and
telecommunication. The other two features seem unique to medicine. It is true
that spending initially increased after nonmedical technical advances, but the
fraction of national income spent did not increase dramatically after the
initial phase of widespread acceptance. On the contrary, technological
development lowered cost, so that the fraction of national income spent
on food, transportation, communication, and much more has gone down, releasing
resources to produce new products or services. Similarly, there seems no
counterpart in these other areas to the rising dissatisfaction with the
delivery of medical care.
International Comparison
These
developments in medicine have been worldwide. By their very nature, scientific
advances know no geographic boundaries. Data on spending are readily available
for 29 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries.
In every one, medical spending has gone up significantly both in
inflation-adjusted dollars per person and as a fraction of national income. In
1997, the United States spent 14 percent of gross domestic product on medical
care, the highest of any OECD country. Germany was a distant second at 11 percent;
Turkey was the lowest at 4 percent.
A
key difference between medical care and the other technological revolutions is
the role of government. In other technological revolutions, the initiative,
financing, production, and distribution were primarily private, though
government sometimes played a supporting or regulatory role. In medical care,
government has come to play a leading role in financing, producing, and
delivering medical service. Direct government spending on health care exceeds
75 percent of total health spending for 15 OECD countries. The United States is
next to the lowest of the 29 countries, at 46 percent. In addition, some
governments indirectly subsidize medical care through favorable tax treatment.
For the United States, such subsidization raises the fraction of health
spending financed directly or indirectly by government to more than 50 percent.
. .
Why Third-Party Payment?
Two
simple observations are key to explaining both the high level of spending on
medical care and the dissatisfaction with that spending. The first is that most
payments to physicians or hospitals or other caregivers for medical care are
made not by the patient but by a third party—an insurance company or employer
or governmental body. The second is that nobody spends somebody else’s money as
wisely or as frugally as he spends his own. These statements apply equally to
other OECD countries. They do not by themselves explain why the United States
spends so much more than other countries. . .
We
have become so accustomed to employer-provided medical care that we regard it
as part of the natural order. Yet it is thoroughly illogical. Why single out
medical care? Food is more essential to life than medical care. Why not exempt
the cost of food from taxes if provided by the employer? Why not return to the
much-reviled company store when workers were in effect paid in kind rather than
in cash?
The
revival of the company store for medicine has less to do with logic than pure
chance. It is a wonderful example of how one bad government policy leads to
another. During World War II, the government financed much wartime spending by
printing money while, at the same time, imposing wage and price controls. The
resulting repressed inflation produced shortages of many goods and services,
including labor. Firms competing to acquire labor at government-controlled
wages started to offer medical care as a fringe benefit. That benefit proved
particularly attractive to workers and spread rapidly.
Initially,
employers did not report the value of the fringe benefit to the Internal
Revenue Service as part of their workers’ wages. It took some time before the
IRS realized what was going on. When it did, it issued regulations requiring
employers to include the value of medical care as part of reported employees’
wages. By this time, workers had become accustomed to the tax exemption of that
particular fringe benefit and made a big fuss. Congress responded by
legislating that medical care provided by employers should be tax-exempt.
Effect of Third-Party Payment on Medical
Costs
The
tax exemption of employer-provided medical care has two different effects, both
of which raise health costs. First, it leads employees to rely on their
employer, rather than themselves, to make arrangements for medical care. Yet
employees are likely to do a better job of monitoring medical care
providers—because it is in their own interest—than is the employer or the
insurance company or companies designated by the employer. Second, it leads
employees to take a larger fraction of their total remuneration in the form of
medical care than they would if spending on medical care had the same tax
status as other expenditures. . .
A
look at the data is instructive. The effect of tax exemption and the enactment
of Medicare and Medicaid on rising medical costs from 1946 to now is clear.
According to my estimates, the two together accounted for nearly 60 percent of
the total increase in cost. Tax exemption alone accounted for one-third of the
increase in cost; Medicare and Medicaid, one-quarter.
Now
consider a different breakdown of the cost of medical care: between the part
paid directly by the government and the part paid privately. Government’s share
went from an eighth of the total in 1919 to a quarter in 1965 to nearly half in
1997. The rise in the government’s share has been accompanied by centralization
of spending—away from state and local governments to the federal government. We
are headed toward completely socialized medicine and are already halfway there,
if, in addition to direct costs, we include indirect tax subsidies.
Expressed
as a fraction of national income, spending on medical care went from 3 percent
of the national income in 1919 to 4.5 percent in 1946 to 7 percent in 1965 to a
mind-boggling 17 percent in 1997. No other country in the world approaches that
level of spending as a fraction of national income no matter how its medical
care is organized. The changing role of medical care in the U.S. economy is
truly breathtaking. To illustrate, in 1946, seven times as much was spent on
food, beverages, and tobacco as on medical care; in 1996, 50 years later, more
was spent on medical care than on food, beverages, and tobacco.
The Changing Meaning of Insurance
Employer
financing of medical care has caused the term insurance to acquire a
rather different meaning in medicine than in most other contexts. We generally
rely on insurance to protect us against events that are highly unlikely to
occur but that involve large losses if they do occur—major catastrophes, not
minor, regularly recurring expenses. We insure our houses against loss from
fire, not against the cost of having to cut the lawn. We insure our cars
against liability to others or major damage, not against having to pay for
gasoline. Yet in medicine, it has become common to rely on insurance to pay for
regular medical examinations and often for prescriptions. . .
If
the tax exemption for employer-provided medical care and Medicare and Medicaid
had never been enacted, the insurance market for medical care would probably
have developed as other insurance markets have. The typical form of medical
insurance would have been catastrophic insurance (i.e., insurance with a very
high deductible).
The Black Hole of Bureaucratization
Third-party
payment has required the bureaucratization of medical care and, in the process,
has changed the character of the relation between physicians (or other
caregivers) and patients. A medical transaction is not simply between a
caregiver and a patient; it has to be approved as "covered" by a bureaucrat
and the appropriate payment authorized. The patient—the recipient of the
medical care—has little or no incentive to be concerned about the cost since
it’s somebody else’s money. The caregiver has become, in effect, an employee of
the insurance company or, in the case of Medicare and Medicaid, of the
government. The patient is no longer the one, and the only one, the caregiver
has to serve. An inescapable result is that the interest of the patient is
often in direct conflict with the interest of the caregiver’s ultimate
employer. That has been manifest in public dissatisfaction with the
increasingly impersonal character of medical care.
Some
years ago, the British physician Max Gammon, after an extensive study of the
British system of socialized medicine, formulated what he called "the
theory of bureaucratic displacement." He observed that in "a
bureaucratic system . . . increase in expenditure will be matched by fall
in production. . . . Such systems will act rather like ‘black holes,’ in
the economic universe, simultaneously sucking in resources, and shrinking in
terms of ‘emitted production.’" Gammon’s observations for the British
system have their exact parallel in the partly socialized U.S. medical system.
Here, too, input has been going up sharply relative to output. This tendency
can be documented particularly clearly for hospitals, thanks to the
availability of high-quality data for a long period.
The
data document a drastic decline in output over the past half century. From 1946
to 1996, the number of beds per 1,000 population fell by more than 60 percent;
the fraction of beds occupied, by more than 20 percent. In sharp contrast, input
skyrocketed. Hospital personnel per occupied bed multiplied ninefold, and
cost per patient day, adjusted for inflation, an astounding fortyfold, from $30
in 1946 to $1,200 in 1996. A major engine of these changes was the enactment of
Medicare and Medicaid in 1965. A mild rise in input was turned into a meteoric
rise; a mild fall in output, into a rapid decline. Hospital days per person per
year were cut by two-thirds, from three days in 1946 to an average of less than
a day by 1996.
Taken
by itself, the decline in hospital days is evidence of progress in medical
science. A healthy population needs less hospitalization, and advances in
science and medical technology have reduced the length of hospital stays and
increased outpatient surgery. Progress in medical science may well explain most
of the decline in output; it does not explain much, if any, of the rise in input
per unit of output. True, medical machines have become more complex. However,
in other areas where there has been great technical progress—whether it be
agriculture or telephones or steel or automobiles or aviation or, most
recently,computers and the Internet—progress has led to a reduction, not an
increase, in cost per unit of output. Why is medicine an exception? Gammon’s
law, not medical miracles, was clearly at work. The provision of medical care
as an untaxed fringe benefit by employers, and then the federal government’s
assumption of responsibility for hospital and medical care of the elderly and
the poor, provided a fresh pool of money. And there was no shortage of takers.
Growing costs, in turn, led to more regulation of hospitals and medical care,
further increasing administrative costs and leading to the bureaucratization
that is so prominent a feature of medical care today. . .
Expected
longevity went from 47 years in 1900 to 68 years in 1950, a truly remarkable
rise. From 1950 on, expected longevity continued to increase but at a much
slower rate, reaching 76 years in 1997. For our purposes, it is of fundamental
importance that, whatever its source, the increase in longevity did not have
any systematic relation to spending on medical care as a fraction of income.
On
the evidence to date, it is hard to see that we have gotten much for
quadrupling the share of the nation’s income spent on medical care other than
bureaucratization and widespread dissatisfaction with the economic organization
of medical care. . .
Conclusion: Medical Savings Accounts and
Beyond
The
high cost and inequitable character of our medical care system are the direct
result of our steady movement toward reliance on third-party payment. A cure
requires reversing course, reprivatizing medical care by eliminating most
third-party payment, and restoring the role of insurance to providing
protection against major medical catastrophes.
The
ideal way to do that would be to reverse past actions: repeal the tax exemption
of employer-provided medical care; terminate Medicare and Medicaid; deregulate
most insurance; and restrict the role of the government, preferably state and
local rather than federal, to financing care for the hard cases. However, the
vested interests that have grown up around the existing system, and the tyranny
of the status quo, clearly make that solution not feasible politically. Yet it
is worth stating the ideal as a guide to judging whether proposed incremental
changes are in the right direction.
Most
changes made in the final decade of the twentieth century were in the wrong
direction. Despite rejection of the sweeping socialization of medicine proposed
by Hillary Clinton, subsequent incremental changes have expanded the role of
government, increased regulation of medical practice, and further constrained
the terms of medical insurance, thereby raising its cost and increasing the
fraction of individuals who choose or are forced to go without insurance.
There
is one exception, which, though minor in current scope, is pregnant of future
possibilities. The Kassebaum-Kennedy Bill, passed in 1996 after lengthy and
acrimonious debate, included a narrowly limited four-year pilot program
authorizing medical savings accounts. A medical savings account enables
individuals to deposit tax-free funds in an account usable only for medical
expense, provided they have a high-deductible insurance policy that limits the
maximum out-of-pocket expense. As noted earlier, it eliminates third-party
payment except for major medical expenses and is thus a movement very much in
the right direction. By extending tax exemption to all medical expenses whether
paid by the employer or not, it eliminates the present bias in favor of
employer-provided medical care. That too is a move in the right direction.
However, the extension of tax exemption increases the bias in favor of medical
care compared to other household expenditures. This effect would tend to
increase the implicit government subsidy for medical care, which would be a
step in the wrong direction.
Before
this pilot project, a number of large companies (e.g., Quaker Oats, Forbes,
Golden Rule Insurance Company) had offered their employees the choice of a
medical savings account instead of the usual low-deductible employer-provided
insurance policy. In each case, the employer purchased a high-deductible major
medical insurance policy for the employee and deposited a stated sum, generally
about half of the deductible, in a medical savings account for the employee.
That sum could be used by the employee for medical care. Any part not used
during the year was the property of the employee and had to be included in
taxable income. Despite the loss of the tax exemption, this alternative has
generally been very popular with both employers and employees. It has reduced
costs for the employer and empowered the employee, eliminating much third-party
payment.
Medical
savings accounts offer one way to resolve the growing financial and
administrative problems of Medicare and Medicaid. It seems clear from private
experience that a program along these lines would be less expensive and
bureaucratic than the current system and more satisfactory to the participants.
In effect, it would be a way to voucherize Medicare and Medicaid. It would
enable participants to spend their own money on themselves for routine medical
care and medical problems, rather than having to go through HMOs and insurance
companies, while at the same time providing protection against medical
catastrophes.
A
more radical reform would, first, end both Medicare and Medicaid, at least for
new entrants, and replace them by providing every family in the United States
with catastrophic insurance (i.e., a major medical policy with a high
deductible). Second, it would end tax exemption of employer-provided medical
care. And, third, it would remove the restrictive regulations that are now
imposed on medical insurance—hard to justify with universal catastrophic
insurance.
This
reform would solve the problem of the currently medically uninsured, eliminate most
of the bureaucratic structure, free medical practitioners from an increasingly
heavy burden of paperwork and regulation, and lead many employers and employees
to convert employer-provided medical care into a higher cash wage. The taxpayer
would save money because total government costs would plummet. The family would
be relieved of one of its major concerns—the possibility of being impoverished
by a major medical catastrophe—and most could readily finance the remaining
medical costs. Families would once again have an incentive to monitor the
providers of medical care and to establish the kind of personal relations with
them that were once customary. The demonstrated efficiency of private
enterprise would have a chance to improve the quality and lower the cost of
medical care. The first question asked of a patient entering a hospital might
once again become "What’s wrong?" not "What’s your
insurance?"
A
longer version of this essay appeared in Public Interest, winter 2001.
Available from the Hoover Press is To America’s Health: A Proposal to Reform
the Food and Drug Administration, by Henry I. Miller. Also available is The
Essence of Friedman, edited by Kurt R. Leube. To order, call 800-935-2882.
Milton Friedman, recipient of the 1976 Nobel Memorial Prize
for economic science, was a senior research fellow at the Hoover Institution
from 1977 to 2006. He passed away on Nov. 16, 2006. He was also the Paul
Snowden Russell Distinguished Service Professor Emeritus of Economics at the
University of Chicago, where he taught from 1946 to 1976, and a member of the
research staff of the National Bureau of Economic Research from 1937 to 1981.
Read the entire
history at www.hoover.org/publications/digest/3459466.html.
Government is not the solution
to our problems, government is the problem.
- Ronald Reagan
* * * * *
5. Lean
HealthCare: The Most Energetic Area of
Lean Practice
James Womack: How do we judge the progress of the Lean Movement? One critical indicator is our success in extending lean thinking to new industries and activities. In recent years I have been greatly encouraged that lean thinking is moving far beyond its origins in manufacturing to distribution, retailing, maintenance and overhaul, consumer services, construction, and – perhaps most striking – healthcare. Indeed, the latter may be the most energetic area of lean practice today.
There is much consolidation going
on in the health care industry. Groups are merging; Hospitals are merging,
ancillary facilities are merging; all in the name of efficiency. What is over
looked, is that no value is created with like firms merge. These actions quickly shift wealth from
customers, employees, suppliers, and former owners to the new owners. This may
do more good than harm, because otherwise the firm in question may completely
fail. But it is often unclear that any additional value has been created in the
sense of better satisfying customer needs with a given amount of human effort
and capital investment. And, from society’s standpoint, the only way to
increase living standards is to change the ratio of human effort and capital
going into firms to the amount of value coming out. Otherwise the outcome is
basically zero- sum, with some winners and some losers.
By contrast, the objective of a lean transformation is to analyze the core value creating processes of organizations in light of customer needs (which may have changed), then figure out how to create more value with the same resources so the organizations can grow and society can prosper. It’s the difference between shifting wealth from one party to another and creating more value, ideally value that can be shared with customers, employees, suppliers and owners. (Note that Womack never uses the term “adding value” because this is an accounting convention for the difference between the input costs of a firm and its output prices. Often Womack finds that only cost is added by the firm as inputs are converted to outputs, not value from the customer’s [or patient’s] standpoint.)
Managers (and owners) will try anything that is quick and easy even if it doesn’t work before they try anything long and hard that does work (e.g. intense process analysis linked to customer needs to create more value from the same resources.
We thank James Womack for keeping us informed of the lean enterprise goals and will follow through with relevance to health care, which he feels is one of the “more energetic areas of lean practice today.”
Please peruse the Lean Enterprise
Institute, at www.lean.org.
* * * * *
6. Medical Myths: Who
pays for the uninsured?
(Fortune Magazine) -- Voters are more worried about
health care than about Iraq, according to recent polls, making it a key
political issue - and leading many health insurance company CEOs to keep their
heads down. Aetna's Ron Williams has been an exception, speaking up on many
major issues, though declining to endorse any candidate's health-care proposal.
Formerly Blue Cross of California's president, Williams came to Aetna as COO in
2001 when the company was on the brink of failure. He and CEO Jack Rowe
engineered a turnaround that increased the company's value from $3 billion then
to $21 billion today. Williams succeeded Rowe as CEO in 2006. Before an
audience in the Time & Life Building in Manhattan, Williams sat down with
Fortune's Geoff Colvin.
In most industries rising revenues are regarded as
good. Why is it that in health care, rising revenues are regarded as a grave
national problem?
I think the U.S. is conflicted. When it comes to our
own health care, we all want the best - access to the latest and most important
technology. At the same time, health care is typically purchased in an
institutional setting. So we purchase it in the aggregate, but we consume it as
individuals. Today the U.S. spends about $2.2 trillion a year on health care.
As an industry we have to do a better job of describing how we help people get
access to the health care they need and improve the quality of care they're
given, and how that $2.2 trillion could easily have been $2.4 trillion.
Why does the U.S. spend so much more per capita than
any other country?
We are a wealthy country. We also are the global
engine of innovation in health care, whether it's the pharmaceutical industry
or the creation of medical devices. Our health-care delivery system is
different from many others in that we have a smaller group of primary-care or
family-practice physicians and a much larger base of specialists. There's at
least one economist who argues that the increase in health-care costs has
actually been a positive in the context of productivity in health in the U.S.
So in a lot of ways we're getting what we want, which is more health care, more
access, and more technology. . .
When buying health care, most of us don't behave like
regular consumers. Seven out of eight dollars we spend is somebody else's
money, and we don't have very good information about doctors or hospitals.
What's the outlook for better information?
At Aetna, in 35 markets, you can go online and know
what your physician will charge you before you see that physician. That's
helpful for a routine service, but when it comes to, say, a serious cardiac
condition, what you really want to know is whether this is a high-quality
physician. We think there is data available. There's going to be a huge
transformation in this area.
Who are the uninsured, and how can we get them
covered?
I'm always amazed that 20% of the 47 million uninsured
are eligible today for Medicaid or the Children's Health Insurance Program.
They could sign up and have a relationship with a primary-care physician. About
10% of the 47 million are college and university students, very inexpensive to
insure. Slightly more than 20% are not citizens but are in the country legally.
We might find a way to link visa entry or other
mechanisms with comprehensive coverage. And about 20% have household incomes
above $75,000. On this we agree with many of the presidential candidates. Aetna
believes there is a place for an individual coverage requirement for
individuals who can afford insurance. I think reasonable people could agree
that at some point there's enough income that someone should be expected to
participate in the health-care system. That leaves us with about 14 million to
17 million who really need tax credits and subsidies or tax deductions.
An individual coverage requirement would force people
to buy what you sell. Tell me why this is the best solution.
Today we all pay for the uninsured. If an individual
sticks up a bank and walks off with $25,000, there are consequences. If someone
who really could have had an insurance policy consumes $25,000 worth of health
care, everyone else pays for that. The average employer is paying 12% more in
premiums today to cover the uninsured than they would pay if we brought those
47 million into the system. So for every group we bring in, health care becomes
more affordable.
Is it going to be possible for consumers to get
comparable data and be able to choose a doctor the way they choose a car?
I think it will be possible within three to five
years. Important efforts are under way, with the collaboration of physicians,
to agree on quality standards. There's collaboration in the industry for all health
plans to pool their data to create very rich data sets. So consumers could look
at a set of performance indicators that physicians think are appropriate, and
be able to judge how their physicians fare.
Explain the strategy behind Aetna's introduction of an
online system to provide medical information.
Every person should have a personal health record. I
have a personal record. When I log on to the secure, password-protected site, I
see the physicians, pharmacists, dentists - everyone who delivers care to me. I
see all the tests and procedures that I've had. I see the lab values. And I can
supplement that data with family history. If my mother, for example, had breast
cancer, that's important for a physician to understand.
Many people think the last thing they want to tell
their health insurance company is that their mom had cancer.
The industry was very careful in establishing
standards. We have agreed that the data would be transferred from plan A to
plan B only after the member was already enrolled in the plan, so the data
could not be used for medical underwriting purposes or to deny anyone access to
health insurance.
What about genetic information?
Our former CEO, Jack Rowe, helped us develop a policy,
which the industry adopted, that we would not use genetic information for
underwriting purposes. We also put in place reimbursement for genetic testing
where the tests can inform the treatment. For example, if a woman has breast
cancer, we will pay for the genetic tests associated with determining the type
of cancer she has.
We may be on the verge of an age of miracles, but
these new treatments could be very expensive. Is there a risk of a social
crisis because not everyone will be able to afford these treatments?
If we're not careful, we're going to have a situation
where people who have comprehensive coverage have access to everything, and
people without have access to very little. So we have to focus on comparative
effectiveness. Physicians and experts should study the science and reach a
conclusion about what courses of treatment and technology give society a good
payback. It's not necessarily a role we should have as insurance companies. But
I think as a society we need mechanisms that help us allocate those dollars so
everyone has access to something, and we don't invest strictly in high tech.
Health care is a tax-free benefit if your employer
buys it, but if you buy it for yourself, you have to use after-tax dollars.
Does that make sense?
No. I do not think it makes sense. We need to provide
the same tax incentives to individuals to buy their own health insurance. It's
also important to recognize that one of the biggest expenses a retired couple
will have is health-care services. So things like health savings accounts,
health reimbursement accounts, and special savings accounts will help people
directly, or with the assistance of their employer they can set money aside to
fund their co-pay and cost-sharing requirement. Tax equality in that regard is
something we would support. . .
Senator Clinton in particular loves to pound on the
health-care insurance industry. Why isn't the industry better liked, and is
that ever going to change?
We do sit in a very uncomfortable intersection. We
have the employer whom we lay out the health plans to, and we say, "You
can buy good, better, or best." We have the employees who, when they make
a plan selection, are thinking about their family budget and not necessarily
about the car wreck or the health problem that's around the corner.
Physicians, whom we understand and try to collaborate
with, really are concerned with delivering high-quality care, being good
advocates for their patients as individuals, and receiving maximum
reimbursement for their services. So it's a pretty uncomfortable intersection.
And when the employee calls up and says, "I have a plan in which my cost
sharing is 20%. How come I don't have a plan where my cost sharing is 5%?"
we've found it not to be great for business to say, "We offered your
employer one, and he chose the one you've got."
What were the most important factors in your becoming
the CEO of Aetna (AET, Fortune 500)?
A willingness to reinvent myself and to recognize that
when one has a set of aspirations, and you reach them, there's a huge
opportunity to ask yourself what more you can do.
I've been very fortunate. I've worked with some great
executives. I grew up in a generation that didn't have a lot of role models who
looked like me in the business community. So I've been very deeply committed to
increasing diversity in our company and in the industry.
I had a great academic experience. MIT's Sloan School
of Management was a terrific school, and it helped transform me from a
functional specialist into a real generalist who had a more strategic point of
view and perspective. I've always been one who sought out challenges and
troubled situations, because I have found that you learn a lot in taking a
chaotic situation and creating structure, process, and strategy. I'd have to
say luck counts too. Staying healthy counts, which is extremely important.
UnitedHealth catches the managed-care flu
http://money.cnn.com/2008/04/29/magazines/fortune/colvin_aetna_csuite.fortune/index.htm
'We all pay for the uninsured'
* * * * *
7. Overheard on Capital Hill: Neoconservatism
Neoconservatism:
An Obituary for an Idea (CD) By C.
Bradley Thompson
This lecture examines the intellectual history of the
neoconservatives and their plan for governing America. Dr. Thompson introduces
the neocons by tracing the evolution of their thought from their youthful
Trotskyism in the 1930s to their anticommunist liberalism in the 1940s and '50s
and finally to their development of a new kind of conservatism in the 1960s and
beyond.
The neoconservatives are generally regarded to be the
most intellectually impressive faction of the post-war intellectual Right: they
seem to take ideas seriously, they seem to be principled, they seem to support
the principles of the American founding, and they seem to support capitalism.
But, as Dr. Thompson demonstrates, behind their rhetorical façade, the neocons
scorn principles, they scorn morality, they scorn capitalism and, ultimately,
they scorn America. Despite their pro-American rhetoric and their appeals to,
and defense of, America's ideals and institutions, Dr. Thompson demonstrates
that the neoconservatives advocate singularly un-American principles: mysticism
over reason, altruism over egoism, duty over rights, collectivism over
individualism, socialism over capitalism, war and empire over peace and trade.
Dr. Thompson's lecture focuses on the neocons' attempt
to transform the Republican Party and the conservative intellectual movement
into a permanent ruling majority, their pragmatic philosophical method, their
advocacy of a conservative welfare state, and their attempt to turn America
toward a form of Platonic republicanism. Ultimately, he argues, the
neoconservatives are a threat to a free society.
(CD;
2-CD set; 90 min., with Q & A)
www.aynrandbookstore2.com/prodinfo.asp?number=CT01M
* * * * *
8.
What's New in
US Health Care: The Presidential Elections
Candidates
and Health Care Reform, by Grace-Marie Turner in the Seattle Post-Intelligencer,
May 13, 2008
Sens.
Barack Obama and John McCain are gearing up for a general election battle --
barring a surprise surge by Sen. Hillary Clinton -- in which they will offer
very different visions for health care reform.
Obama --
like Clinton -- sees a much larger role for government in the one-sixth of our
economy represented by the health sector. Obama would mandate that all children
have health insurance, would require employers to pay for insurance for their
workers, would impose significant new federal regulation over health insurance
and would expand government programs such as Medicaid.
McCain
has a very different vision. "The key to real reform is to restore control
over our health care system to the patients themselves," he said recently
He would
focus on new financing tools to help people buy health insurance that would be
portable from job to job, new mechanisms for those with pre-existing conditions
to get coverage, and he would emphasize prevention and better care
coordination, especially for people with chronic illnesses.
Obama and
McCain agree the key to health reform is getting costs under control. "The
reason Americans don't have health insurance isn't because they don't want it,
it's because they can't afford it," Obama says. As a result, neither
candidate supports a universal mandate for health insurance.
But Obama
would lock in the employment-based system with new mandates on employers.
McCain
sees a world in which, "Americans (have) new choices beyond those offered
in employment-based coverage." He believes that "Americans want a
system built so wherever you go and wherever you work, your health plan goes
with you."
McCain
would boost options for individually owned health insurance by making everyone
eligible for a refundable tax credit to help them buy health insurance. He
would allow people to purchase health insurance across state lines and would
give states new incentives and resources to make sure everyone has access to
coverage. He says that bringing millions of new buyers into the health care
marketplace will expand competition and force insurers and providers to offer
more affordable options.
Obama
believes government should require insurers to accept all applicants and would
force insurers to charge basically the same premium for everyone, regardless of
age, gender, occupation or pre-existing conditions. A healthy young person
would pay about the same as a 62-year-old with heart disease and diabetes.
Obama
wants a national "pay or play" mandate, forcing employers to cover a
preset percentage of their workers' health insurance or pay a fine. Some
businesses would be partially subsidized, but that would mean significant
federal oversight of all employer health spending.
He would
expand Medicaid and the State Children's Health Insurance Program and would
create a new program modeled on Medicare. That would force private health plans
to compete with a taxpayer-supported public insurance program, which has
federal policing authority and the ability to impose price controls -- hardly a
level playing field.
Congress
will wrestle with the intricacies of reform, but in this election year, the
vision is the key, and the contrast between the visions that Obama and McCain
offer is stark. The bottom line question will be whether individuals or
government will be in control of health care in the future.
Grace-Marie
Turner is president of the Galen Institute, a nonprofit research organization
focusing on free-market solutions to health reform. She is speaking Tuesday at
Washington Policy Center's sixth annual health care conference at the Sea-Tac
Doubletree Hotel. For more information call 206-937-9691 or visit www.washingtonpolicy.org.
www.galen.org/component,8/action,show_content/id,13/blog_id,1047/category_id,2/type,33/
* * * * *
9. Health Plan USA:
Disruptive Technology: Not All Patients Want High-Tech Care
The federal
government is trying to foist the Electronic Medical Record down the throats of
the medical establishment. They consider this as evolving and improvement.
However, it is disruptive in the worse sense of the term. It may be disruptive
technology, but it is not disruption innovation. Dr. Clayton Christensen has
some valuable lessons for health care. (See World Health Care Congress
presentations.)
The term disruptive technology was
coined by Clayton M.
Christensen and introduced in his 1995 article Disruptive Technologies: Catching the
Wave, which he coauthored with Joseph Bower. The purpose of the
book is aimed at managing executives who make the funding/purchasing decisions
in companies rather than the research community. He describes the term further
in his 1997 book The Innovator's Dilemma.
In his sequel, The Innovator's Solution,
Christensen replaced disruptive technology with the term disruptive
innovation because he recognized that few technologies are intrinsically
disruptive or sustaining in character. It is the strategy or business model
that the technology enables that creates the disruptive impact. The concept of
disruptive technology continues a long tradition of the identification of
radical technical change in the study of innovation by economists, and the
development of tools for its management at a firm or policy level.
How low-end disruption occurs
over time
Christensen distinguishes
between "low-end disruption" which targets customers who do not need
the full performance valued by customers at the high-end of the market and
"new-market disruption" which targets customers who have needs that
were previously unserved by existing incumbents.
"Low-end
disruption" occurs when the rate at which products improve exceeds the
rate at which customers can adopt the new performance. Therefore, at some point
the performance of the product overshoots the needs of certain customer
segments. At this point, a disruptive technology may enter the market and
provide a product which has lower performance than the incumbent but which
exceeds the requirements of certain segments, thereby gaining a foothold in the
market.
In low-end disruption,
the disruptor is focused initially on serving the least profitable customer,
who is happy with a good enough product. This type of customer is not willing
to pay premium for enhancements in product functionality. Once the disruptor
has gained foot hold in this customer segment, it seeks to improve its profit
margin. To get higher profit margins, the disruptor needs to enter the segment
where the customer is willing to pay a little more for higher quality. To
ensure this quality in its product, the disruptor needs to innovate. The
incumbent will not do much to retain its share in a not so profitable segment,
and will move up-market and focus on its more attractive customers. After a
number of such encounters, the incumbent is squeezed into smaller markets than
it was previously serving. And then finally the disruptive technology meets the
demands of the most profitable segment and drives the established company out
of the market.
"New market
disruption" occurs when a product fits a new or emerging market segment
that is not being served by existing incumbents in the industry. The Linux operating
system (OS) when introduced was inferior in performance to other server
operating systems like Unix
and Windows
NT. But the Linux OS is inexpensive compared to other server operating
systems. After years of improvements Linux is now installed in 84.6% of the
worlds 500 fastest supercomputers.[1]
Not all technologies
promoted as disruptive innovations have actually prospered as well as their
proponents had hoped. However, some of these technologies have only been around
for a few years, and their ultimate fate has not yet been determined.
Unresolved examples of
technologies promoted as 'disruptive innovations'
Disruptive technologies
are not always disruptive to customers, and often take a long time before they
are significantly disruptive to established companies. They are often difficult
to recognize. Indeed, as Christensen points out and studies have shown, it is
often entirely rational for incumbent companies to ignore disruptive
innovations, since they compare so badly with existing technologies or
products, and the deceptively small market available for a disruptive
innovation is often very small compared to the market for the established
technology.
Even if a disruptive
innovation is recognized, existing businesses are often reluctant to take
advantage of it, since it would involve competing with their existing (and more
profitable) technological approach. Christensen recommends that existing firms
watch for these innovations, invest in small firms that might adopt these
innovations, and continue to push technological demands in their core market so
that performance stays above what disruptive technologies can achieve.
Disruptive technologies,
too, can be subtly disruptive, rather than prominently so. Examples include
digital photography (the sharp decline in consumer demand for common 35mm print
film has had a deleterious effect on free-riders such as slide and infrared
film stocks, which are now more expensive to produce) and IP/Internet
telephony, where the replacement technology does not, and sometimes cannot
practically replace all of the non-obvious attributes of the older system
(sustained operation through municipal power outages, national security
priority access, the higher degree of obviousness that the service may be
life-safety critical or deserving of higher restoration priority in catastrophes,
etc).
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Clayton_M._Christensen
www.12manage.com/methods_christensen_disruptive_innovation.html
* * * * *
10. Restoring Accountability in Medical Practice by Nonparticipation in
Government Programs and Understanding the Devastating Force of Government
·
Medicine and Liberty –
Network of Liberty Oriented Doctors, www.MedLib.ch/
Medicine & Liberty (MedLib) is an independent
physician network founded in 2007, dedicated to the study and advocacy of
liberty, ethics & market in medical services.
·
We support professional
autonomy for doctors and liberty of choice for patients
·
We uphold the
Hippocratic covenant that forbids action harmful to the patient
·
We defend responsible
medical practice and access to therapeutic innovation free from bureaucratic
obstruction
·
We work towards a deeper
understanding of the role and importance of liberty & market in medical
services
MedLib
is part of a wide movement of ideas that defends
·
The self-ownership
principle & the property rights of individuals on the products of their
physical and intellectual work
·
Free markets, free
enterprise and strict limits to the role of the State
·
Duane Parade, President of the National Taxpayer’s Union, www.ntu.org/main/, keeps us apprised of all
the taxation challenges our elected officials are trying to foist on us
throughout the United States. To find the organization in your state that’s
trying to keep sanity in our taxation system, click on your state at www.ntu.org/main/groups.php.
·
FIRM: Freedom and
Individual Rights in Medicine, Lin
Zinser, JD, Founder, www.westandfirm.org,
researches and studies the work of scholars and policy experts in the areas
of health care, law, philosophy, and economics to inform and to foster public
debate on the causes and potential solutions of rising costs of health care and
health insurance.
* * * * *
Stay Tuned to
the MedicalTuesday and the HealthPlanUSA Networks and have your friends do the
same.
Articles that appear in MedicalTuesday and
HPUSA may not reflect the opinion of the editorial staff. Sections 1-7, 9 are
entirely attributable quotes in the interest of the health care debate.
Editorial comments
are in brackets.
ALSO NOTE:
MedicalTuesday receives no government, foundation, or private funds. The entire
cost of the website URLs, website posting, distribution, managing editor, email
editor, and the research and writing is solely paid for and donated by the
Founding Editor, while continuing his Pulmonary Practice, as a service to his
patients, his profession, and in the public interest for his country.
* * * * *
Del Meyer
Del
Meyer, MD, CEO & Founder
HealthPlanUSA,
LLC
6945 Fair Oaks Blvd, Ste A-2, Carmichael, CA 95608
Words
of Wisdom
When the government seeks to enforce a counterfeit
right—such as the “right” to medical care—no expansion of freedom results.
Instead, government power expands—to everyone’s detriment. –Sheldon Richman
Washington is no
place for a civilized man to spend the summer. –President James Buchanan,
1857-1861.
Washington is
not a place to live in. The rents are high, the food is bad, the dust is
disgusting and the morals are deplorable.
–Horace Greeley, July 13, 1865.
There are a
number of things wrong with Washington. One of them is that everyone has been
too long away from home. –President Dwight D. Eisenhower, May 11, 1955
Some
Recent Postings
www.healthplanusa.net/NewsLetterIntro.htm
www.healthplanusa.net/January08.htm
www.HealthPlanUSA.net/April08.htm
www.HealthPlanUSA.net/July08.htm
This
Month in History - July
This is Freedom Month. It was not given that distinction
because it is the beginning of the most popular vacation month-July; freedom
from the daily grind is fine but the kind of freedom that July represents is
somewhat more basic.
July 1 is Freedom Day because it marks the beginning of the month in which so
many nations, including our own, gained their freedom. Canada became a
self-governing dominion of Great Britain on this day in 1867. France celebrates
the anniversary of its first revolution on July 14. Such other nations as
Algeria, Argentina, Colombia, Belgium, Peru, Liberia and Venezuela gained
self-government and freedom during this month. So our theme today is freedom—freedom
seen from several points of view: first, how do we keep it and second, what do
we do with it. Third, I suggest, how strongly are we committed to it.
On July 1, 1863, was the
beginning of the Battle of Gettysburg in 1863, a battle memorable both for the
bravery and dedication of those who fought it and for its role as a turning
point in the Civil War. The Battle of Gettysburg, as Abraham Lincoln said a few
months later, must be remembered so that from its honored dead “we take
increased devotion to that cause for which they gave the last full measure of
devotion.” In the largest sense, that cause was, again as Lincoln said, “that
government of the people, by the people, for the people shall not perish from
the earth.”
On July 1, 1966, Medicare—the idea of providing care for those
who, by reason of age, are both the most vulnerable to illness and the least
able to pay for help—went into effect in the United. As Medicare has
evolved over the next 40 years, can we be certain that our gluttonous utilization
of unnecessary health care has not outstripped our resources and left us far
worse off? Perhaps jeopardized the security that it was to prevent? Time will
tell. Perhaps our increased life expectancy was a far better security.
After Leonard and
Thelma Spinrad